000 04375cam a2200433Ki 4500
001 12686
003 MaCbMITP
005 20210629145709.0
006 m o d
007 cr cnu---unuuu
008 200821s2020 maua ob 001 0 eng d
040 _aOCoLC-P
_beng
_erda
_epn
_cOCoLC-P
020 _a0262358638
_q(electronic book)
020 _a9780262358637
_q(electronic book)
020 _z9780262044042
_q(hardcover)
020 _z0262044048
_q(hardcover)
035 _a(OCoLC)1187209134
035 _a(OCoLC-P)1187209134
050 4 _bG56 2020eb
082 0 4 _a338.82
_223
100 1 _aGilbert, Richard J.,
_d1945-
_9106720
245 1 0 _aInnovation matters :
_bcompetition policy for the high-technology economy /
_cRichard J. Gilbert.
264 1 _aCambridge, Massachusetts :
_bThe MIT Press,
_c[2020]
300 _a1 online resource (viii, 324 pages) :
_billustrations (black and white).
336 _btxt
337 _bc
338 _bcr
500 _aIT Carlow ebook
520 _a"Antitrust enforcement has long been focused on price competition-approving or denying mergers based on whether or not it would create or reduce opportunities for consumers to be able to "shop around" for the lowest prices when it comes to internet access, cable subscriptions, airfare, and so on. It is relatively easy to evaluate price impacts-these are qualitative measures and economic theory presents many tools to be able to do so. However, the impact of antitrust policy on innovation is much less well known, and harder to study. Was Microsoft abusing a monopoly by bundling a web browser with its operating system? Would a merger of Genzyme and Novazyme, the only companies with active research and development programs for Pompe Disease promote or delay a cure for this fatal genetic disorder? Is Google's search engine good for consumers or not? This book collects the current state of knowledge about the relationships between market structure, firm behavior, and the production of new products and services, all to provide a clear picture of the challenges of making and enforcing antitrust policy in the digital era. Gilbert addresses the ways in which legal precedents established in the twentieth century no longer hold up in the twenty-first, complicates existing theories by Schumpeter and Arrow about competition, and attempts to make meaning out of the conflicting empirical literature surrounding mergers. Gilbert does not shy away from making recommendations. A few examples: In cases where one firm acquires a competitor, he calls for antitrust enforcement officials and courts to pay more attention to whether acquired firms are successful innovators. In some cases, an incumbent acquiring a new entrant does stymy innovation as there are then fewer firms operating in the same space, but in other cases, people launch start-ups with the hopes of getting bought out by a competitor, and so prohibiting acquisition of a competing firm could limit the number of innovative new companies that are launched. He also discusses the role of interoperability standards in promoting innovation on the one hand, through the economies of scale allowable by knowing that components developed can be used across a number of devices, but also its role in limiting innovation when dominant firms coalesce around a standard that is unreachable by competitors. Gilbert's main argument is that existing antitrust law is flexible enough to be relevant in the digital era, but courts must stop focusing almost exclusively on questions of price and consider a broader range of questions regarding competition and innovation"--
_cProvided by publisher.
588 _aOCLC-licensed vendor bibliographic record.
650 0 _aHigh technology industries.
_9106721
650 0 _aCompetition.
_9106722
650 0 _aAntitrust law
_xEconomic aspects.
_9106723
650 0 _aConsolidation and merger of corporations
_xLaw and legislation
_xEconomic aspects.
_9106724
653 _aECONOMICS/Industrial Organization
653 _aBUSINESS/Innovation
856 4 0 _yLink to MIT Press online resource
_uhttps://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/12686.001.0001?locatt=mode:legacy
856 4 2 _3OCLC metadata license agreement
_uhttp://www.oclc.org/content/dam/oclc/forms/terms/vbrl-201703.pdf
999 _c50772
_d50772